|
Social Security's basic problem: "It's the economy" -- Unfortunately, many members of the general public, as well as Congress -- and even many economists -- talk about "reducing" Social Security with little apparent understanding of the close relationship between Social Security finances and the health of the general economy.
Social Security benefits are not a tax-financed "entitlement." They are a government-sponsored, primarily self-financed insurance program, like many private corporate pension programs used to be. The program's Trust Fund was built up over decades by contributions (not "taxes") from the people who expect -- as in any insurance program -- to receive the benefits they have paid for. The solutions being currently proposed for the system's alleged financial problems involve various methods for reducing those benefits, but fail to respond to the underlying problem.
The relationship to unemployment [1] -- Every spring, the Trustees of the Social Security Trust Fund publish an annual report [2] (2010 version here), which provides very useful statistical appendices. Over the past decade, these have included a chart [3] of three different long-term projections of the system's finances. Here is the most recent version :Clearly, projection "I" is the only one with long-term viability -- a fact largely ignored in virtually all public discourse, which tends to focus, like the Trustees' report, on projection "II." These projections -- the so-called "Low-Cost" (I), "Intermediate" (II), and "High-Cost" (III) -- differ in their assumptions about various contributing factors. These factors are shown in Table II.C.1 of the Trustees' 2010 annual report. A key difference is the Unemployment Rate:
I Low-cost: 4.5% | II Intermediate: 5.5% | III High-cost: 6.5% |
The notion that the U.S. should -- or even could -- tolerate an average
5.5% unemployment for the next 75 years is unconscionable.
Period | Unemployment | Inflation |
---|---|---|
1950:Q4-1953:Q4 | 3.2% | 3.1% |
1955:Q1-1957:Q3 | 4.2% | 3.2% |
1965:Q3-1970:Q1 | 3.8% | 4.0% |
1998:Q2-2001:Q2 | 4.2% | 1.9% |
The average rate of inflation for all these periods was 3.2%; the average for the entire period from 1950-2009 was 3-1/2%. There is no credible reason why our economy, using appropriate tools, cannot be managed so as to maintain stable full employment without inflation, which would greatly improve the environment for both business and labor -- and for Social Security.
"Unemployment Insurance" for Social Security -- Three significant observations offer guidance on the problem of Social Security financing:
These suggest that the best -- and possibly only -- reliable approach to the Social Security problem is to insulate the Trust Fund from two threats to its solvency
The former is beyond the scope of this proposal, which addresses the latter by giving the Trust Fund "unemployment insurance," rather than betraying the trust of the millions of people who have played by the rules and contributed to Social Security for decades. Such an approach would involve
The process could even involve transfers to the general fund when unemployment is brought below the level defined in (a) above, as it was during the periods listed in Table 1, above. The "unemployment insurance" calculation in (b) above is the focus of this discussion of the close relationship between unemployment and Social Security finances.
The Trustees' annual report (Appendix VI, Table A4) provides the financial data [5] that govern the Trust Fund's level of assets, as shown in the Trustees' chart of long-term projections, Figure 1, above.The data series that is of primary interest here is the Net Trust Fund Increase (NTFI), the difference between the Fund's income and expenses. Because it constitutes the growth of the Trust Fund, it is what must be supplemented in recessions by the proposed "unemployment insurance," and its relationship to unemployment is what determines the appropriate level of such supplementation.
Determining the relationship -- Any relationship between two data series is most easily seen in a scatter diagram. This is a plot of points, with one data series on one axis, the other on the other axis. If the points tend to line up, a relationship is likely; if they form a "cloud," a relationship isn't likely.
In looking for a relationship between the NTFI and unemployment, each point represents a year, from 1984 to 2009 [6]. For each point, the Unemployment Rate is plotted on the horizontal axis and the NTFI on the vertical axis. The NTFI values are scaled down using Potential GDP (PGDP) [7]. The resulting scatter diagram looks like this: At first glance, this looks like a cloud, not a line. But because the two data series are time series that extend over time, a relationship that exists at one time may be changed to a different one by changes in policies and economic factors, so that a "cloud" may actually consist of several line-ups of points representing different relationships at different times. To spot this kind of situation, the points are connected and each point labeled with its year date. The result is a date-ordered scatter diagram [8]: This chart offers a number of suggestive line-ups [9] for certain periods:The points falling within these periods can then be tested for correlation using regression lines:
This plot shows the regression lines in periods of recession as dashed red, and those in periods of recovery as solid green. The regression parameters for these lines are shown both on the plot and in Table 2 below. These parameters are:
Calculating the "unemployment insurance" transfer -- As just noted, the slope value for each line indicates the NTFI change for each percent change in the unemployment rate. However, as mentioned above, the chart data uses NTFI as a percent of Potential GDP, which must be converted back to the original billions-of-dollars value to be useful in determining the amount of the transfer. The formula for converting the slope to the dollar value of the NTFI shortfall caused by a one-percent change in unemployment takes this into account:
(1) Shortfall (transfer amount) per percent unemployment = | ( - Slope / 100 ) x Potential GDP |
The ultimate aim of this exercise is the determination of how much money should be transferred to the Trust Fund at a given level of unemployment. The above formula provides the amount for each excess percent of unemployment. The actual final amount is obtained by multiplying that by the excess of the actual unemployment rate over the target rate (e.g., the one suggested above: 4.5%):
(2) "Employment insurance" transfer = | Shortfall per percent unemployment (from formula #1) x ( actual unemployment - 4.5 ) |
Table 2, below, illustrates this process. For each period,
Table 2 | |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
R-squared Value Color Codes
|
|
Yellow column 7 shows the average for the period. In practice, the transfer could be done annually, using year-specific values. If this were to be done for the each of the individual years covered here, the average yearly transfer for each period would remain the same as in yellow column 7 -- but the transfers in the individual years in that period would vary. This is particularly true for the most recent period (2007-09), where excess unemployment amounted to only about 0.3% in 2007, but was 4.8% in 2009. The transfers would have been insignificant in 2007, but quite significant in 2009. [10]
Conclusion -- The decision on what to do about Social Security is not separable from what to do about the economy, nor from the moral and financial responsibilities of the federal government to its citizens.
This proposal -- the provision of "unemployment insurance" to insulate the Trust Fund from fluctuations in unemployment -- clearly maintains the government's moral and financial responsibility by honoring the financial commitment made by the millions of participants in Social Security. The proposal also clearly adds Social Security to the group of economic factors known as the automatic stabilizers, which tend to increase deficits in depressed times and increase surpluses in good times, a manifestation of the fact that appropriate federal government spending is the best -- and sometimes the only -- way to end a depression.
Deficit hawks should take note that the automatic stabilizers create a surprisingly large automatic deficit component during times of high unemployment. Currently, this is creating an automatic debt for taxpayers of about $60 billion for each excess percent of unemployment above 4%, for a total of over $300 billion a year.
We have a choice. This automatic deficit is wasted money, money that could be used to rebuild our on-the-edge infrastructure and create jobs -- that is, to invest in lower future deficits by pulling us out of this depression, and reducing the need for supplementation of Social Security's finances. Yes, we do have a choice.
Net Trust Fund Increase Total Trust Fund Income Income excluding Interest (i.e., contributions, taxes) Interest [11] Cost (98-99% of which is benefits) |
Written: December 11, 2010
Last revised: February 22, 2011 |
|