|
Contents
|
In the 2000 election campaign both parties promised to put Social Security (SS) and Medicare Baby-Boom surpluses in a "lock box" and not raid them for non-SS purposes. But that promise was broken even before the 9/11 terrorist attack, by Bush's budget-busting tax cut and the recession. Now those promises seem entirely out the window. Congress seems set to "spend what it takes" to repair the attack damage and win the "war" against terrorism -- without much concern about how that spending will be paid for. Since Bush seems to have little interest in addressing, or even acknowledging, the aspects of US foreign policy that have fueled Arab/Muslim anger, that war and its costs are likely to escalate sharply.
In the interest of "bipartisan national unity," the Democrats have refrained from demanding cancellation of Bush's future tax cuts or opposing his star wars research, and have even offered to cut back on their own long-sought education and other social investment plans. But the Administration is hinting that it wants to take advantage of the crisis to get more tax cuts for business and the wealthy under the banner of "fiscal stimulus." Thus, it now seems likely that the whole SS surplus will soon go to financing non-SS deficits, as before 1998. It would be a real tragedy if this crisis leads to a repetition of the Reagan/Bush fiscal irresponsibility of the 1980s that spent the entire SS surplus and quadrupled the federal debt and its interest burden on taxpayers. That would be very expensive "collateral damage" from the terrorist attack.
This article suggests that the best way of preventing this outcome would be to use the crisis to make some long-needed basic reforms in how we deal with the budget and Social Security finances -- fiscally and economically sound changes that will make both of them easier to understand, easier to manage, and less vulnerable to political shenanigans.
Before the 9/11 attack such a Policy Budget would have projected a 2002 (non-SS) surplus perhaps $80-100 billion more than the comparable unified budget -- enough to have gotten Congress out of its pre-attack "fiscal straightjacket" with less partisan wrangling. Now this budget would tell more clearly -- and more non-partisanly -- than the unified budget how much fiscally responsible "wartime" tax-cut reduction and/or tax increase is needed to pay for post-attack spending increases. The CBO should make a preliminary projection on this basis as soon as possible.
To be most efficient, a pro-active increase in the Stabilization Account deficit should be viewed in a credit-flow perspective, as a complement to Fed monetary policy. The economically most appropriate amount would increase the economy's total demand for credit (federal, business, consumer and state/local borrowing) just enough to counter recession-induced "pushing on a string" credit conditions -- as perhaps best indicated by the "real" Federal Funds rate. The Fed can then increase the money supply (M1) at an adequate recovery rate without pushing the real Fed Funds rate below zero (as in Japan!) and causing a precipitous reduction in the dollar exchange rate. (Cf. "Monetary and Fiscal Policy Sunshine Act")
(Note: In this article, the term "Baby-Boom" is used with SS surpluses and reserves as an explicit political reminder of this vital purpose of the large and rapidly-growing SS trust fund.)
Just as for private pension funds, SS's large and rapidly growing interest earnings on its investments are vital for its long run financial health. But when SS is permitted to invest only in Treasury bonds, the Treasury's interest payments to SS are, in effect, a large taxpayer subsidy of SS that greatly reduces the real non-SS budget surplus. The present unified budget scam effectively hides this cost the same way it hid the pre-1998 non-SS deficits -- by subtracting SS interest receipts from the Treasury's total interest payments. This way, the cost becomes evident only after 2020 when the Treasury has to find the money to pay off the interest-financed SS bonds. Permitting SS to invest in private debt securities would "privatize" this interest cost and correspondingly increase the (non-SS) Policy Budget surplus. The 2002 increase of over $65 billion would finance a significant portion of the post-attack increase in spending.
This reform would obviously protect Baby Boom reserves from being raided for non-SS purposes much more effectively than the flimsy "lock box" promises -- and would make the SS trust fund seem more "real" to those who doubt SS's future. It would also make it unnecessary to pay off the entire public debt, some of which now plays a useful role in the management of monetary policy and private pension and insurance businesses. A further advantage of initiating this reform at this time is that, because of the recession, the interest rate "spread" between Treasury and private bonds and mortgages is much higher than usual. So the SS trust fund, which can afford to take a longer-run perspective than most private investors, can benefit from the higher rates at the same time that its security purchases tend to reduce the rates for private borrowers -- and help the housing industry.
Not mere smoke-and-mirror gimmicks. These reforms are fundamental conceptual changes that increase the "transparency" (understandability) of the SS and budget systems, reduce the incentive for short-run political gamesmanship in budget making, and facilitate real fiscal and economic responsibility. For instance, they would help clarify the distinction between the public debt and the national debt (which includes Treasury debt to both SS and the public). This would help expose the basic misconception that Treasury borrowing from the SS trust fund to pay down the public debt also reduces the total national debt. These reforms would also help throw more light on a fact conveniently ignored by the privatizers -- that the overall social and economic "burden" of retiree benefits on future workers, and the effects on financial markets, will be much the same, whether the anticipatory prior financial saving is through Social Security or through private pensions and 401(k)s.
Basis for a political deal. The larger non-SS Policy Budget surpluses resulting from these reforms would make possible needed spending increases without raiding SS Baby-Boom surpluses. Traditional fiscal conservatives would not need to fight for counter-productive across-the-board spending cuts. Liberal Democrats could fight for badly needed investment spending without divisively denouncing as Coolidge/Hoover "balanced budget theology" the fiscally responsible desire to reduce the high interest cost in the federal budget. Democratic supporters of Bush's tax cut could also work for more social spending. But in the present political environment in which Congress wants to maintain at least a façade of "wartime bipartisan national unity," the budget framework of these reforms would also tend to provide a strong check on Bush's tendency to Reagan-like fiscal irresponsibility.
In an 8/24 news conference Bush referred to the "fiscal straightjacket" his tax cut and the recession had imposed on Congress as "incredibly positive news" -- because it would halt growth of the federal government (except for his proposed military increases). If the Democrats allow the Republicans to use this crisis to wipe out the SS surplus and run big non-SS deficits, as during the 1980s, they can kiss goodbye to their hopes for more social spending and will have no platform on which to run a winning campaign in 2002 and 2004.
These budget and SS reforms create a budget framework that makes it easier to demand fiscal responsibility of the Republicans and also provides better bargaining power for the inevitable compromises. If the Democrats push these through now, history could well look back on them with the same approval it now looks back on Clinton's hard fought 1993 fiscal "revolution." If the Republicans block them, they will provide key planks to run on in 2002 and 2004.
A potential political bargaining chip to support efforts to rescind Bush's budget-busting tax cut and keep a lid on his military spending increases. Since Bush measures the "size of government" by the non-military portion of the budget, it is worth noting that the Reagan/Bush regime -- which the current Bush seems to be imitating -- greatly increased the "size of government" by the huge slice of interest cost that its fiscally irresponsible fourfold increase in federal debt added to later budget pie charts. As a reminder of this lesson, it might be useful to initiate -- and hold hearings on -- a proposal to include in current Bush Policy Budgets a "sinking fund" amount equal to 20% of the interest cost of the part of the public debt added by the Reagan/Bush regime.
Written: September 12, 2001
Last revised: September 25, 2001 |
|